Alaudin Khilji Market Reforms
Adarsh Saini
The reign of Alauddin Khalji was marked by a period of expansion, conquests and annexation as well as the brave counter to the Mongols. In addition to the military achievements of Alauddin, his reign was also well known for the agrarian and market reforms which were introduced by the Sultan. They highlighted the need of the state for additional revenue which could have been possible only through state intervention.
Contrary to the opinions of some scholars like Moreland, information about Alauddin’s reforms would have been available had Barani’s work not been present. A number of contemporary historians have propounded their view points about this particular issue. Amir Khusrau had written his Khaza’inu-l Futuh in 1311 or soon after; Ibn Battuta’s Rihla was written during the period he was in Delhi (1335-1342); Isami devoted a section of his book-Futuh-us Salatin- to this particular topic in 1350 and even the Chisti mystic Nasiruddin Mahmud had spoken on this topic twice at some length in his conversations recorded in 1354-55. However, most of these accounts only provided a factual information about these reforms without giving an indepth analysis of the same; most of the time even the information was neglected or incomplete. It was Barani’s ‘Tarikh-I Firuz-Shahi written in 1357, which provides a full account of the market reforms which took place during the reign of Alauddin Khalji along with his own opinions on the same.
These reforms had come up as a possible solution to a critical financial problem. This was caused by the constant stream of invasions of the Mongol army for which Alauddin Khalji had to undertake a vast amount of expenditure. Fortified walls had to be thrown around Delhi, the damaged forts had to be rebuilt and strengthened and a number of new walls were also created. All these fortified settlements had to be stocked with grains and a large standing army had to be maintained at all times, with well-trained, equipped soldiers and good horses. These troopers had to be paid a regular annual salary as well. Khalji believed that if such an army was paid in cash on a regular basis than the royal treasury would be empty within a few years.
He
worked out a system by which a fully equipped soldier maintaining one horse would
be paid 234 tankas and a soldier maintaining two horses was to be paid 78
tankas extra. But such low payments could be put into effect only if the troops
were still able to get all the articles and animals they were required to
maintain and also such goods and services as were necessary for the maintenance
or subsistence of their families, slaves and servants. Thus, Alauddin attempted
the mechanism of pushing down prices of these goods without hurting his
military ambitions.
However,
some scholars have objected to this on the grounds that Alauddin had regulated
and reduced the prices of all commodities, even those which had no importance
for the military. However, other scholars have countered this by stating that
the chief objective was not to merely cheapen the military stores and horses,
but also reduce the salaries of the cavalrymen and other troopers. However, to
ensure that these people were able to enjoy other goods as well for the basic
subsistence pattern it was necessary to reduce the prices of all goods, whether
directly required by the troopers or not.
Some
scholars on the basis of Nasiruddin Mahmud’s writings believe that Alauddin’s
market reforms were aimed at the general welfare of the people. Alauddin,
apparently, wanted to do something beneficial for the people. He considered
giving up his wealth but realized that it would not reach out to everyone. As a
result, he decided to reduce the prices of the grains as the benefits of that
would accrue to everyone living in his empire. This view was also supported by
the writings of Amir Khusrau.
The
essence of Khalji’s reforms was to bring the villages in closer association
with the government in area extending from Dipalpur and Lahore to Kara near
modern Allahabad. In this region, the villages were to be brought under Khalisa;
lands assigned in charitable grants were also confiscated and brought under the
khalisa. The Sultan decreed that three taxes were to be levied on the peasantry
viz. the Kharaj or the land-tax; a grazing tax (charai) on cattle and ghari on
houses or huts. As far as Khiraj was concerned, the land under cultivation was
measured; the yield was estimated per unit area; and then by multiplying the
area by the yield the total produce was to be worked out. Half of the produce
thus determined was to be exacted uniformly from every peasant without
exception.
A
significant feature of rural agriculture in India was the existence of a large
number of intermediaries. At the village level there was the village head,
called the chaudhari or muqaddam. Alauddin’s agrarian reforms implied putting
greater pressure for the displacement of the rais or ranas, who were chiefs
controlling a trace of land which was parceled out to his clan and other
supporters for collecting land-revenue. In the areas brought under the khalisa,
Alauddin tried to curb the privileges of the zamindars, muqaddams and
chaudharis. These sections formed the rural aristocracy and according to
Barani, they were rich enough to ride Arabi and Iraqi horses, wear weapons and
fine clothes and indulge in wine drinking. Their wealth was based on holding
the best land in the villages. Moreover, in a system where the village was
assessed as a whole, they often passed on the burden of their share of the land
revenue on to the shoulders of the weak.
Alauddin
took stringent measures against this section of society forcing them to pay the
grazing and housing taxes like the others and as a result of the system of
measurement of area under cultivation to determine the land revenue he prevented
them from passing on the burden to someone else. Although, he was unable to
offset the trend of land redistribution in the rural areas he was able to
infuse a fear of punishment among the rural elite, which made them more
obedient and ensured regular payment of land revenue. A contemporary source
states “their obedience reached such a pitch that a footman from the town
revenue office would tie the necks of twenty zamindars, muqaddams and
chaudharis together and kick and thrash them for the realization of tribute”.
While
reforming the agrarian system, Alauddin tried to ensure the efficient and
honest working of the machinery of revenue administration. This was done by
appointing a large number of accountants, collectors and agents in a very short
span of time. The accountants of all these officials were audited strictly by
the wazir and even if one jital was out of place they were to be punished
severely.
Alauddin
was more or less the first ruler who looked at the problem of price control in
a systematic manner and was able to maintain stable prices over a considerable
period of time. Alauddin had set up three markets at Delhi, the first for food
grains, the second for cloth of all kinds, and for expensive items such as
sugar, ghee, oil, dry fruits etc and the third for horses, slaves and cattle.
Detailed regulations were framed for the control and administration of all
these markets.
In
order to control the food prices, Alauddin attempted to control the supply of
food grains from the villages, its transportation to the city by the grain
merchants and its proper distribution to the citizens. Alauddin’s first effort
was to see that there were sufficient stocks of food grains with the government
so that the traders did not try to raise the prices by creating an artificial
scarcity or indulging in profiteering. For this purpose royal stores were setup at Delhi. However, Barani had raised the
question “how were the Sultan’s grain store-houses so full that they had enough
within them to replace normal supplies whenever these failed in the bad
season?”
The
answer to this question was rooted in Alauddin’s land-tax policy. As stated
above, this was half of the produce and in addition taxes were also imposed on
the milch cattle and houses. As a result of these high tax demands, and the
strict measures adopted to collect these taxes, Alauddin was able to obtain
half the agricultural produce for the state. Moreover, Alauddin had made it
very clear that grains alone should be collected from all areas in the khalisa
in lieu of land-tax, while in all areas lying in the eastern part of Rajasthan
only half the revenue was to be collected in grain, the remainder in cash. Thus, in this way the royal stores always had
enough of a stock to face any food crisis. According to Barani “There was no
mohalla in Delhi in which two or three houses were not fully stocked with the
Sultan’s grain”.
The
task of transporting these grains was
undertaken by banjaras, some of whom had 10,000 or 20,000 bullocks. These
banjaras were ordered to form themselves into one corporate body, giving
sureties for each other. They were to settle on the banks of Jamuna with their
wives, children, goods and cattle. An official was appointed to oversee them.
In fact, in normal times these banjaras were able to bring in so much food
grains into the city that it was not necessary to touch the royal stores.
To
ensure the regular supply of grains to the banjaras, a number of regulations
were made. In the areas, which had been brought under the khalisa, the local
officials were charged with the responsibility of ensuring that the grains
would be delivered by the cultivator to the grain merchant at a cash price from
their fields. Alauddin ordered the Royal
Finance Ministry should take letters from the officials and collectors to say
that they would demand the land-tax from the peasants with such harshness that
the latter would not be able to bring the grain from the fields into their
houses and engross it, and would be forced to sell the grains at low rates by
the side of the field to the grain carrier. As a result of this regulation, the
grain-carriers found no obstacle in conveying grain to the market and grain
supplies constantly reached the market. For their own profit, villagers also
brought whatever they could from the fields to the market and sold it at prices
fixed by the Sultan. These regulations were imposed mostly in the assigned
territories, where the grain was not taken in revenue, but the tax in money was
to be so rigorously demanded so as to force the peasant to sell part of his
grain to pay the tax.
If
the cultivator wished to sell more they could do so but the local officials were asked to sign a bond
that said they would not permit anyone to regrate or sell at a price higher
than the official price. Anyone who violated this rule were severely punished
and the regrated grains were confiscated. All the food grains were to be
brought to the market for food-grains set up by Alauddin and sold only at
official prices.
Thus,
grain supplies at low prices depended upon the extraction of the agrarian
surplus through the land-tax, brought directly into the Sultan’s granaries or
into the grain-carriers’ hands by the rigour of the tax demand. The Sultan then
fixed low prices arbitrarily, which were then enforced in the urban market, by
assuring continuous supply of grains. As a result of all these measures there
was an adequate supply of food grains in the towns because of which the prices
fell. Wheat was sold for 7.5 jital per man, barley for 4 jital, superior
quality rice for 5 jital etc. an officer, with an adequate force was also
appointed in charge of the market with strict instructions to anyone who tried
to raise the price. “So long as Alauddin lived, monsson or no monsoon, there
was not the slightest rise in these prices. The permanence of prices in the
grain market was a wonder of the age”.
Alauddin
received daily reports about the activities of the market from three different
sources- controller of the market, intelligence officers and lastly from secret
spies who had been appointed for this very purpose. Thus, people tended to
behave properly as they were aware of the fact that Alauddin’s spies were
informing him about everything.
Alauddin
had also instituted a system of rationing during the times of scarcity. Each
grocer was issued an amount of grains from the government stores bearing in
mind the population of the ward. No individual was allowed to buy more than
half a man at one time. However, the amount was more for nobles who did not
have villages of lands of their own. As a result of these measures, even during
the time of famine there was no shortage of food-grains at Delhi and even the
price of food-grains did not increase.
The
second market was called sarai-i-adl.
It was an exclusive and to a large extent a subsidized market for manufactured
commodities and merchandise brought from a long distance, from territories
outside the Sultan’s dominion and even from foreign countries. The first
regulation with regard to this market was the setting up of a separate market
by itself for these commodities. Alauddin had ordered that cloth brought from
different parts of the country including foreign lands, was to be stored and
sold only in this market at government rates. To ensure an adequate supply of
all the commodities, all merchants whether Hindu or Muslim, were registered with
the ministry of commerce and their business was to be regulated. A deed was
taken from these merchants, who had been importing commodities into the city, that
they would bring the same quantities of commodities to this market every year,
and sell them at government rates. The “regulated” merchants brought so much
merchandise from the provinces and adjoining territories that it accumulated in
the market and was left unsold for many years.
However,
as most of these goods were imported from outside the price-control zone,
Alauddin’s price regulation measures did not apply to these goods. As a result,
there was a stark difference between the cost in the place of origin and the
retail price at Delhi. The prime costs could not be reduced but other measures
were taken to bridge this gap. The rich Multani merchants i.e. those who
brought commodities from long-distances including foreign countries, were given
an advance of 20 lakh tankas from the treasury, on condition that they did not
sell them to any intermediaries but at the market at official rates. The power
and responsibilities for obeying these orders were given to a body of merchants
themselves. Finally, a permit officer was appointed. Alauddin believed that
many of the items available in this market were of extremely high quality and
were not required by the general public. Thus, these products were not to be
sold to anyone, until and unless, the permit officer wrote out a permit. This
was done to ensure that costly cloth was not purchased by people and given to
others who would take it out of Delhi, and sold in the neighbouring towns at
four or five times the price, an officer was appointed to issue permits to
amirs, maliks etc for the purchase of these costly commodities in accordance
with their income.
The
prices of the commodities even in this market were quite cheap. Thus, for one
tanka a person could buy 40 yards of coarse, or 20 yards of fine-woven cotton
cloth, one ser of coarse sugar for 1 ½ jital, ½ ser of ghee for 1 jital, 3 ser
of oil for 1 jital etc.
The
third market dealt with horses, cattle
and slaves. The horse trade was more or less a monopolistic trade, with the
overland trade being monopolized by Multanis and Afghans. But they were sold in
the market by middlemen or dallals.
The
horse merchants had become a severe headache for the Sultan. According to the
procedure of that day, a man who wanted service with the cavalry had to provide
himself with one or two horses and the necessary equipment and then appear at
the review, where he was inspected by the officer-in-charge. If he was found
fit, the price of the horse would be paid to him. But since most horsemen could
not afford to pay the price of their horses before the review, persons with
money found the purchase and stabling of horses a good investment. They entered
into an alliance with the leading brokers, who not only helped them to raise
the price but also took a commission from both the horsemen and the
horse-merchants.
Alauddin
took harsh measures against such merchants. They were banished from the town,
and some of them were imprisoned in forts. A stern order was issue that no
horse-merchant or capitalist was to purchase a horse directly or through an
agent or come anywhere near the horse-market. Then, with the hep of other
dallals, the quality and price of the horses were fixed. Horses of high quality
were priced between 100 and 120 tankas, those of the second category 80 to 90
tankas and those of the third 65 to 70 tankas. The price of ordinary horses,
which were not used in the army was 10 to 25 tankas.
The
prices of the slave boys and girls and of cattle were also fixed. The reasons
for doing this are slightly unclear but its believed that these measures were
taken to make the life of the nobles or richer sections of society easier, who
had become accustomed to buying slaves for domestic and personal service.
Likewise, animals were needed for meat, transport and for milk and milk
products.
The
general markets, scattered throughout the city, were put under the control of
the Department of Commerce. Alauddin did not interfere in this arrangement but
he made sure that every commodity’s price was fixed irrespective of how
insignificant it may have been-hats, comb, betel leaf, needles, sugarcane etc. Alauddin
had selected a ruthless and shrewd minister of commerce who was able to keep
the shopkeepers under control. The minister would regularly check the prices of
goods in the market and thrash the shopkeepers ruthlessly for charging above
the price list. These severities compelled the shopkeepers to reduce their
prices, but they did not give up all tricks, such as using false weights,
keeping aside their best commodities and telling lies to young and ignorant
purchasers. As a last measure Alauddin would send children to the markets to
purchase goods. The minister would then make inquiries into these purchases and
if the shopkeeper had charged over the price list then double his body weight
would be carved out of the flesh of the shopkeeper.
It
is not possible to define the territory in which Alauddin Khalji’s price
measures were effective. Barani speaks as if the prices were set for Delhi; but
it is reasonable to infer that the same prices also prevailed in the
surrounding areas, which could offer an alternative market to these products.
This probably included the entire Khalisa region where the land revenue system
was instituted by Alauddin. It is unlikely that price control measures extended
to areas outside of this region. A letter in Mahru suggests that prices were
kept low under Alauddin in Multan and Ucch as well; but a closer scrutiny of
these texts suggests that he comparing the state of affairs in Delhi at the
time of that sultan with contemporary conditions in Ucch.
Many of Barani’s contemporaries praised Alauddin immensely for instituting these measures. Amir khusrau looked upon these measures as an act of generosity on part of the Sultan, undertaken for the sake of “general comfort, the welfare of the elect and the public at large’ and ‘of the general benefit of the city-man and the villager”. Ibn Battuta noted how “the people of the hind greatly praised Alauddin on this account.” Isami lauded the measures for the relief that it brought to the people and Nasiruddin Mahmud recounted how the Sultan was anxious to do something from which ‘gain would accrue to all the people’. Similarly, even Barani in his first account had praised the Sultan for implementing these measures.
However,
in his later accounts he was far more discriminating in assessments of the
benefits flowing from price-control. The entire fabric rested on a very heavy
agrarian taxation. The peasants had to part with half their produce and this
was collected in such a harsh manner that they were forced to sell all the
grain and could not hold back any surplus for stocking or for engrossing. The
market reforms had left the peasantry with so little as to be “barely enough
for carrying on cultivation and his food requirements. The peasantry was
completely impoverished during the reign of Alauddin and could not even raise a
voice against the harsh treatment meted out to them by the officials.
Large
segments of the upper rural population were also greatly impoverished as they
themselves became subject to tax-demand and were forbidden to levy their
cesses. No longer could “the chaudhris, zamindars and muqaddams ride horses,
wield arms, wear good clothes or chew betel leaf”; even the women of the lords
had to take service in Muslims’ houses. Part of the grain and other rural
products, which these classes consumed, must have now gone to Delhi and the
other towns in tax-payment, thereby augmenting supplies over there.
The
gains from the low prices within the city were also not universal. While, some
citizens were benefitted by the rationing system as it ensured a regular food
supply during famines. A major section of the population who seems to have had
its real income reduced was that of the artisans and the unskilled labourers
and servants. This arose because of the fall in the prices of the goods, which
they used to sell in order to obtain their income. According to Nasiruddin
Mahmud, during the reign of Alauddin a tailor could make a robe for 4 or 6
jitals, whereas in his time-1354-no less than 48 jital would be charged for.
Similarly, Barani also stated that wages of labourers in Alauddin’s time were a
fourth of what they were under his successors. Thus, under Alauddin there was a
general lack of money in the hands of the people.
Though
the ‘market men’ suffered the proper merchants had a fairly respectable
position in Alauddin’s reign; the Multanis indeed received large treasury loans
to encourage them to bring supplies of luxury goods from distant places.
The
principal gainers of all these moves seem to have been the nobles. According to
Barani, under Alauddin “things came to such a pass that except for the houses
of the nobles and commanders, officials and Multanis little money was to be
found anywhere else”. Their revenues were significantly contracted but their
purchasing power was unaffected; they also had a saved up treasury which would
have firther enhanced this purchasing power. Moreover, the revenue collected
outside the limits of the zone where commutation prices had been reduced would
be on the old scale, and yet be worth far more in Delhi in terms of goods. The
special provision for supply of high quality cloth, restricted to the nobility
or the cheap supply of slaves and good horses clearly shows the concern for the
welfare of the nobility.
Alauddin
Khalji had seen the need to regulate markets and prices in order to be able to
afford a large standing army which could counter the perpetual Mongol threat.
He was successful as far as the reduction in prices was concerned. The market
prices of all goods from horses to grains to cloth to insignificant items
remained low and at the fixed price as set by the Sultan. This had enabled him
to organize a large army and also increase the wealth of the treasury
marginally. However, the extremely harsh measures used to ensure this had
caused a great deal of pain and suffering to the common people. Some of the
people in fact were fed up of their lives and wished for death as they could no
longer take such a strict control.
Thus,
shortly after the death of Alauddin his price control system collapsed; under
his successor Qutbuddin Mubarak Khalji prices rose rapidly and the wages went
up ‘four times’. He also released the prisoners who had been imprisoned for
selling commodities at prices above the fixed rate. Moreover, he withdrew the
laws which, to some extent, denied people the freedom to eat, wear, speak or
buy or sell what they wanted. The regulations of Alauddin had also resulted in
a lot of bureaucratic controls and thus corruption. His policy would have been
more successful had he controlled the prices of only a few essential
commodities or those meant for direct use by the military. However, he
controlled the prices of everything; such centralized control were bound to
lead to violations, inviting punishments and thus resentment. Hence, by their
very nature, Alauddin’s market reforms were temporary and largely meant to tide
over an emergency, or a particular situation.